Impacts of GMTZ Policy on Scarcity of Admission Places of Good Public Junior Middle Schools: Evidence from Housing Price
Yu Xiaofen1,2, Zhang Jinyuan2, Zhang Yanjiang1,2
1.China Academe of Housing & Real Estate, Zhejiang University of Technology, Hangzhou 310014, China 2.School of Management, Zhejiang University of Technology, Hangzhou 310023, China
Abstract:It has been a long-standing challenge to improve the coordination between government and society in better providing public goods. The basic education (elementary and junior middle schools) provision is one typical example. At the end of the last century, to promote the development of private schools to address the shortage of basic public education, the Chinese government gave out several important privileges. For example, private schools could start admissions much earlier than public schools and set specific admission requirements on students, and rejection by private schools did not influence a student’s admission by public schools. Private schools could also admit students across districts without being limited by school zones and charge much higher tuition fees. With these privileges, private schools gained rapid development and a much better reputation for education quality than public schools. That generated new problems: (1) characterized by high tuition fees and high admission requirements on students or even on parents, good private schools could only benefit the rich, which added to education inequality; (2) good private schools could admit the best students and take away the best teachers, which largely harmed the education quality and thus the reputation of public schools.To address the above problems, the Chinese government issued in June 2019 a policy that removes most of the privileges of private schools. Specifically, the policy requires a student to choose between a public and a private junior middle school in his first round of admission application and requires a private school to admit students within the administrative district where it is registered (hereafter the GMTZ policy). As a result, the GMTZ policy raises the risk for a student to apply for good private school; in the meantime, it raises the chances of students within the administrative districts that have abundant good private schools.This study focuses on the GMTZ policy in terms of junior middle schools in Hangzhou and investigates how the policy changes the housing price premiums associated with the right to be admitted by the public junior middle school of good education achievements (hereafter, good public school premium) to reveal how the GMTZ policy impacts the scarcity of admission places of good public junior middle schools.Applying a DID model and DDD model, we reach four findings based on the records of pre-owned housing. First, we demonstrate that the GMTZ policy significantly adds to the scarcity of admission places of good public junior middle schools and raises the housing price premiums associated with good public junior middle schools by 153,500 yuan. Second, we find that the closer a residential area is to high-quality private junior middle schools, the more substantial the housing price premium is raised by the GMTZ policy. This implies that the GMTZ policy reduces the substitution of a good private school with a good public school. The logic is that before the implementation of the GMTZ policy, good private school is more attractive for students located in an area that is closer to the school because of the convenience of commuting to the school, and private school has stronger substitution to good public schools and thus inhibits the good public school premium; after the GMTZ, the risk of being admitted by the private school is substantially raised, and thus, the substitution effect is largely removed, and the good public school premium is boosted. Third, in the administrative district where admission places of good private junior middle schools are relatively increased by the GMTZ policy, the good public school premiums are less raised. This implies that the GMTZ policy raises the substation of good private schools to good public schools by raising accessibility to good private schools, and thus, good public school premiums are relatively inhibited. The second and third findings demonstrate that the mechanism of how the GMTZ policy adds to the scarcity of admission places of good public junior middle schools is that it reduces the substitution of good private schools with good public schools. Finally, we also find that the GMTZ policy motivates high-income families which prefer high housing quality to shift from quality private schools to chasing quality public schools, and that reveals the behavioral foundation of the substitution mechanism. Robustness tests, including parallel trend tests and different levels of sensitivity tests, are conducted, and consistent results are obtained.This study makes the following three major contributions. First, it contributes to the literature in studying education-related policies by revealing how a policy changes the substitution effect of private schools for public schools and thus changes the scarcity of public education. Second, this paper is one of the initial studies to investigate education and housing price problems from the perspective of government-society coordination in providing public goods, which has important implications for improving the coordination mechanism between governments and the society in the provision of public goods. Third, it further discusses the micro behavioral fundamentals of how an education policy triggers the sorting of residents.
虞晓芬, 张金源, 张燕江. “公民同招”如何影响优质公办学位稀缺性[J]. 浙江大学学报(人文社会科学版), 2024, 54(1): 80-98.
Yu Xiaofen, Zhang Jinyuan, Zhang Yanjiang. Impacts of GMTZ Policy on Scarcity of Admission Places of Good Public Junior Middle Schools: Evidence from Housing Price. JOURNAL OF ZHEJIANG UNIVERSITY, 2024, 54(1): 80-98.
1 姜晓萍、吴宝家: 《人民至上:党的十八大以来我国完善基本公共服务的历程、成就与经验》,《管理世界》2022年第10期,第56-70页。 2 范黎波、刘佳: 《形成政府与社会组织共同提供公共服务的合力》,《光明日报》2022年1月25日,第11版。 3 徐海燕: 《比较视角下社会资与公共服务市场化的经验与路径》,《深圳大学学报(人文社会科学版)》2022年第4期,第86-95页。 4 吴结兵、钱倩严慧、程远: 《共同生产行为与公共服务感知绩效:对环境治理的一个跨层次分析》,《浙江大学学报(人文社会科学版)》2022年第1期,第22-38页。 5 张舜禹、郁建兴、朱心怡: 《政府与社会组织合作治理的形成机制——一个组织间构建共识性认知的分析框架》,《浙江大学学报(人文社会科学版)》2022年第1期,第67-81页。 6 唐雪梅、何小路: 《私立学校能否抑制学区房溢价?——来自上海市重点小学与二手房价格数据的实证分析》,《经济学动态》2021年第2期,第95-109页。 7 张传勇、赵柘锦、王天宇: 《民办学校、学区房溢价与基础教育资源的空间配置》,《经济学(季刊)》2022年第4期,第1383-1404页。 8 Tiebout C. M., “A pure theory of local expenditure,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 64, No. 5 (1956), pp. 416-424. 9 Black S. E.,“Do better schools matter? parental valuation of elementary education,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114, No. 2 (1999), pp. 577-599. 10 温海珍、杨尚、秦中伏: 《城市教育配套对住宅价格的影响:基于公共品资本化视角的实证分析》,《中国土地科学》2013年第1期,第34-40页。 11 胡婉旸、郑思齐、王锐: 《学区房的溢价究竟有多大:利用“租买不同权”和配对回归的实证估计》,《经济学(季刊)》2014年第3期,第1195-1214页。 12 Chan J., Fang X. & Wang Z. et al., “Valuing primary schools in urban China,” https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2019.1031832, 2023-09-10. 13 韩璇、沈艳、赵波: 《房价中的优质教育溢价评估——以北京市为例》,《经济学(季刊)》2020年第5期,第257-276页。 14 邵磊、任强、侯一麟: 《基础教育均等化措施的房地产资本化效应》,《世界经济》2020年第11期,第78-101页。 15 孙伟增、林嘉瑜: 《教育资源供给能够降低学区房溢价吗?——来自北京市新建小学的证据》,《经济学(季刊)》2020年第2期,第499-520页。 16 Fack G. & Grenet J., “When do better schools raise housing prices? evidence from Paris public and private schools,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 94, No. 1-2 (2010), pp. 59-77. 17 Wang J. & Li G.,“Pursuing educational equality and divergence in the housing market: how do educational equality policies affect housing prices in Shanghai?” https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2022.104001, 2023-09-10. 18 冯晗、陈海敏、周洪: 《公民同招改革与学区房溢价变化——基于杭州二手房交易微观数据的研究》,《中国经济问题》2022年第5期,第182-196页。 19 孙军、程晋宽: 《义务教育学校“公民同招”制度的设计与推进》,《中国教育学刊》2020年第7期,第44-49页。 20 Wen H., Xiao Y. & Zhang L., “School district, education quality, and housing price: evidence from a natural experiment in Hangzhou China,” https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2017.03.008, 2023-09-10. 21 石绍宾、鞠镇远: 《教育资本化效应的再测度——基于“零择校”政策的学区房溢价断点回归》,《南开经济研究》2022年第8期,第139-157,175页。 22 Peng Y., Tian C. & Wen H., “How does school district adjustment affect housing prices: an empirical investigation from Hangzhou, China,” https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chieco.2021.101683, 2023-09-10. 23 Agarwal S., Li K. & Qin Y. et al., “Tax evasion, capital gains taxes, and the housing marke,” https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2020.104222, 2023-09-10. 24 Zhang Y., Wang X. & Zhang F. et al., “Rumour of administrative division adjustment and regional housing markets: housing listings, prices and speculation,” https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2023.2206633, 2023-09-10.